2.4.4.2 Theory of absolute advantage and comparative advantage
The theories of absolute advantage and comparative advantage are fundamental concepts in international trade theory. Both theories explain how countries can benefit from specializing in the production of certain goods and engaging in trade with other countries. They were first introduced by the classical economists Adam Smith and David Ricardo, respectively.
- Theory of Absolute Advantage: The theory of absolute advantage, proposed by Adam Smith in his seminal work “The Wealth of Nations” (1776), states that a country should specialize in producing goods or services in which it can produce more efficiently than other countries. In other words, a country has an absolute advantage in the production of a good if it can produce more of that good using fewer resources (e.g., labor, capital, and land) than another country.
For example, if Country A can produce 100 units of wheat using 10 units of labor, while Country B can produce the same 100 units of wheat using 15 units of labor, Country A has an absolute advantage in wheat production.
According to the theory of absolute advantage, countries that specialize in producing goods where they have an absolute advantage and engage in trade with other countries can increase overall production and achieve mutual gains from trade.
- Theory of Comparative Advantage: The theory of comparative advantage, developed by David Ricardo in his book “Principles of Political Economy and Taxation” (1817), builds on the concept of opportunity cost. It states that a country should specialize in producing goods or services in which it has a lower opportunity cost of production compared to other countries.
Opportunity cost refers to the value of the next best alternative forgone when a choice is made. In the context of comparative advantage, it refers to the production that a country gives up to produce a certain good.
For example, if Country A can produce 100 units of wheat or 50 units of cloth using 10 units of labor, and Country B can produce 100 units of wheat or 30 units of cloth using 8 units of labor, Country B has a lower opportunity cost of producing cloth (1.25 units of wheat) compared to Country A (2 units of wheat). Therefore, Country B has a comparative advantage in cloth production.
According to the theory of comparative advantage, even if a country does not have an absolute advantage in any good, it can still benefit from specializing in the production of goods where it has a comparative advantage and trading with other countries.
Key Takeaways:
- The theory of absolute advantage focuses on the efficiency of production and suggests that a country should specialize in goods where it can produce more efficiently than others.
- The theory of comparative advantage emphasizes opportunity cost and argues that a country should specialize in goods where it has a lower opportunity cost of production compared to other countries.
- Both theories advocate for specialization and trade as a means to maximize overall production and promote mutual gains from trade.